
Adverse selection insurance occurs when individuals with a higher risk of a certain event, such as a car accident, are more likely to purchase insurance, driving up premiums for everyone else.
This can lead to a situation where only those who are most likely to need the insurance are the ones buying it, leaving the rest of the population without adequate protection.
As a result, the insurance pool becomes less diverse and more expensive, ultimately benefiting the insurers at the expense of the policyholders.
In essence, adverse selection insurance creates a cycle where the very people who need insurance the most are the ones who are priced out of the market.
If this caught your attention, see: Can an Apartment Require Renters Insurance
Adverse Selection
Adverse selection is a major issue in the insurance market, where buyers and sellers have different levels of information about the product or investment. This can lead to problems like the Lemons Problem, where only defective or low-quality products remain on the market.
The Lemons Problem was first identified by economist George A. Akerlof in the 1960s, who used the example of used cars to illustrate how asymmetric information can lead to adverse selection. As a result, the only used cars left on the market are often "lemons".
In the insurance industry, adverse selection can lead to cherry-picking, where insurers only provide coverage to low-risk individuals. This can result in higher costs for society as a whole, as higher-risk individuals are not covered.
Insurers may try to minimize claims by denying coverage to individuals who are deemed "high risk", such as those with preexisting conditions. This practice is known as cherry-picking or cream-skimming.
To combat cherry-picking, some governments require health insurance providers to insure all who apply, at the same cost, regardless of their individual risk factors. This helps to prevent insurers from taking advantage of adverse selection.
Broaden your view: Which Insurers Offer 180 Car Insurance European Cover
Market Impact
Adverse selection can create market inefficiencies that increase prices or prevent transactions from occurring. This happens when some people have more information than others and take advantage of those less-informed, often to their detriment.
In fact, markets are assumed to be efficient in economic theory, but information asymmetries can disrupt this balance. This is why insurers have their own methods of protecting themselves from adverse selection.
One way insurers limit adverse selection is by enforcing enrollment periods, which prevent people from buying insurance only when they need it. This helps prevent the high premium spiral that comes from adverse selection.
Impact on Companies
Insurance companies want to mitigate the risky behavior that moral hazard can put them in.
They examine an individual's background to determine if they're too high-risk for a life insurance policy. Mental health issues, hospitalizations, and health conditions can be red flags.
Insurance companies use various methods to limit moral hazard, such as rewarding good behavior like safe driving or healthy choices.
Some insurance companies penalize bad behavior with higher rates or fees.
To protect themselves from adverse selection, insurance companies take the following actions:
- Examine an individual's background to determine if they're too high-risk for a policy.
- Reward good behavior like safe driving or healthy choices.
- Penalize bad behavior with higher rates or fees.
Textbook Markets Environment
In the textbook case of insurance markets, firms offer a single insurance contract that covers some probabilistic loss, and risk-averse individuals differ only in their privately-known probability of incurring that loss.
Firms compete in prices but do not compete on the coverage features of the insurance contract, which is a key simplifying assumption in this scenario.
Consumers in this market make a binary choice of whether or not to purchase the contract, and firms compete only over what price to charge for the contract.
This setup leads to adverse selection, where consumers with a higher probability of incurring the loss are more likely to purchase the contract, as illustrated in Figure 1.
Additional reading: In Insurance Policies the Insured Is Not Legally
Used Car Market
The used car market is a prime example of how adverse selection can lead to a wrong allocation of resources. This is due to the information asymmetry between buyers and sellers, where the seller often has more knowledge about the car's history and condition.
The seller may also be aware of hidden defects that only they know about, giving them an unfair advantage in the negotiation. As a result, the buyer ends up paying more than the car's actual worth.
In this situation, the seller gains a profit from the sale, but the buyer is left with a potentially problematic vehicle. This highlights the importance of doing thorough research and due diligence when buying a used car.
Ways to Overcome
Insurance companies can use multiple sources to get as much information as possible about a client, reducing information asymmetry and the chance of adverse selection.
Requesting medical information from applicants, such as paramedical examinations and querying doctors' offices for medical records, gives the insurance company more information that an applicant may fail to disclose on their own.
Increasing access to information can minimize asymmetries, making it harder for adverse selection to occur. This can be achieved through crowd-sourced information, such as user reviews and formal reviews by bloggers or specialist websites.
For more insights, see: Adverse Selection vs Asymmetric Information
Warranties and guarantees offered by sellers can also help, allowing consumers to use a product risk-free for a certain period to see if it has flaws or quality issues.
Laws and regulations, such as Lemon Laws in the used car industry, can also help mitigate adverse selection.
Here are some characteristics that can be red flags for insurance companies:
- Mental health/suicide attempts.
- Hospitalizations.
- Risky career or hobbies.
- Health conditions.
Insurance companies can reward good behavior, such as driving safely or making healthy choices, to limit moral hazard. They can also penalize bad behavior with higher rates or fees.
Understanding Adverse Selection
Adverse selection occurs when one party in a negotiation has relevant information the other party lacks, often leading to poor decisions.
This asymmetry of information can cause insurance companies to unknowingly take on higher-risk clients at lower premiums, resulting in financial losses.
Insurance companies address adverse selection by identifying high-risk groups and charging them more money, as seen in the case of life insurance underwriting.
For your interest: Best Third Party Shipping Insurance
Underwriters evaluate applicants' health, medical history, and lifestyle risks to determine the premium to charge, impacting the company's potential for paying a claim.
Asymmetric information is a key factor in adverse selection, where one party has more information than the other, leading to market failure.
In insurance, adverse selection occurs when a high-risk buyer is wrongly considered a low-risk buyer due to asymmetric information, resulting in a disadvantage for the insurance company.
The problem of adverse selection can lead to a "death spiral" and market failure, as insurance companies increase premiums to cover higher costs, driving away low-risk clients.
Adverse selection is called as such because it involves unfavorable or harmful terms for certain groups, often selected to enter into a transaction precisely because they are at a disadvantage.
Consequences and Limitations
Adverse selection can have serious consequences for consumers, including increased costs and lower consumption. This is because buyers often lack the information held by sellers or producers, creating an asymmetry in the market.
Consumers may end up buying overvalued shares or faulty products, which can cause physical harm and negatively impact their health and well-being. This can also lead to a decrease in consumption as buyers become wary of the quality of products being offered for sale.
A lack of information can also exclude certain consumers who cannot afford to obtain it, making it difficult for them to make better buying decisions.
Moral Hazard
Moral hazard occurs when one party has not entered into a contract in good faith or has provided false details about its assets, liabilities, or credit capacity.
It happens after a deal is struck, unlike adverse selection which occurs beforehand. In the investment banking sector, for instance, bank employees may take on excessive risk to score bonuses, knowing the bank will be bailed out if their bets fail.
This imbalance is a result of asymmetric information between two parties, where one party has more private information than the other. It's a problem that can have serious consequences, like higher premiums for policyholders in the insurance industry.
Moral hazard can lead to individuals or companies taking on more risk than they would normally, because they know they'll be protected if things go wrong. This can ultimately result in higher premiums for policyholders.
Recommended read: Capital One Rental Car Insurance
Consequences
Buying a faulty product or a defective vehicle can cause physical harm, which is a direct consequence of adverse selection.
Consumers may refrain from buying certain healthcare products, like medicines or vaccines, if they don't have good information, which can lead to health problems.
A seller's lack of transparency can lead to overcharging, as seen in the secondhand car market where a seller may charge more for a vehicle with a known defect.
Consumers may end up buying overvalued shares, losing money, if they don't have access to the same information as the seller, as in the example of company managers issuing shares when they know the share price is overvalued.
The lack of information can lower consumption, as buyers may be wary of the quality of the products offered for sale, and may exclude certain consumers who cannot afford to obtain information that could lead to better buying decisions.
For your interest: With Disability Income Insurance an Insurance Company May Limit
Public Policy in the Textbook Case

Public policy in the textbook case is often shaped by the government's response to a crisis. The 1906 San Francisco earthquake led to significant changes in building codes and emergency preparedness.
The government's role in public policy is to provide a framework for addressing societal problems. This is evident in the creation of the Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA) in 1979.
FEMA's response to disasters like Hurricane Katrina in 2005 highlighted the importance of coordination between government agencies. The agency's slow response to the disaster led to widespread criticism.
In the case of the 1969 Cuyahoga River fire, public policy focused on environmental protection. The event led to the passage of the Clean Water Act in 1972.
The Clean Water Act has had a lasting impact on water quality regulations. It has also led to increased public awareness of environmental issues.
The government's response to the 2008 financial crisis involved significant policy changes. The Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) was created to stabilize the financial system.
TARP's success in stabilizing the financial system has been debated. However, it is clear that the government's intervention had a significant impact on the economy.
Related reading: Hawaii Condo Insurance Crisis
Core Challenges of Positive Correlation Test

Applying the positive correlation test is not as straightforward as it seems. One of the main challenges is that it can confound adverse selection and moral hazard.
Comparing expected costs across individuals with and without insurance can lead to incorrect conclusions about adverse selection. This is because both adverse selection and moral hazard can generate a positive correlation between insurance coverage and claims.
Moral hazard, in particular, can produce the same "positive correlation" property as adverse selection. This is depicted in Figure 6, which shows an insurance market with moral hazard but no selection.
The flat MC curves in Figure 6 represent the lack of selection, while the two different MC curves represent the expected costs of insured and uninsured individuals. The difference between these curves is a graphical way to quantify moral hazard in terms of expected cost.
Researchers have generally been careful to acknowledge these issues and find creative ways to get around them. However, the challenges in applying the positive correlation test remain a significant limitation of this approach.
For another approach, see: Life Insurance Policy Drug Test
Analyzing Adverse Selection
Adverse selection occurs when individuals with higher risks are more likely to purchase insurance, driving up premiums for everyone. This can lead to a self-fulfilling prophecy where the insurance becomes unaffordable for those who need it most.
For example, if a life insurance company offers a policy to people with pre-existing medical conditions, the company may attract more applicants with these conditions, increasing the likelihood of payouts and thus the premium costs.
Graphical Framework
The graphical framework is a powerful tool for understanding adverse selection in insurance markets. It helps us visualize the concept and its implications.
Empirical research has been using this framework to test for the existence and nature of selection in real-world markets. This research has progressed significantly over the last decade.
A graphical view of selection can help us understand its welfare consequences and those of potential public policy interventions. By using this framework, we can better comprehend the intuition and limitations of empirical research on selection.
Empirical work on selection has flourished over the last decade, and this graphical framework is a key part of that research. It allows us to see how selection manifests in data and what it means for policy makers.
A fresh viewpoint: What Is Insurance and Its Types
Positive Correlation Tests
Empirical research on adverse selection has progressed from detecting its existence to quantifying its welfare consequences and policy interventions.
The positive correlation test is a common approach to testing for adverse selection in insurance markets. This test essentially requires us to test whether the marginal cost (MC) curve is downward sloping.
The early empirical approaches developed strategies to get around the difficulty of making inference about marginal individuals by focusing on comparing averages.
To examine whether adverse selection is present in a particular insurance market, one can compare the expected cost of those with insurance to the expected cost of those without. This can be done by comparing the average expected cost of the insured (ACinsured) to the average expected cost of the uninsured (ACuninsured).
A downward-sloping MC curve implies that ACinsured is always above ACuninsured, with the average costs of the insured at Qmax equal to the average costs of the uninsured at Q = 0.
However, applying the positive correlation test can be challenging due to the potential confounding of adverse selection and moral hazard. Both can generate a positive correlation between insurance coverage and claims.
Moral hazard can produce the same "positive correlation" property as adverse selection, making it difficult to distinguish between the two.
Expand your knowledge: Adverse Selection vs Moral Hazard
Empirical Analysis
Adverse selection insurance is a complex issue that can't be ignored.
In a study of 10,000 insurance applicants, 5% of applicants were found to have a history of making false claims. This suggests that some individuals are more likely to take advantage of insurance policies, which can drive up costs for everyone else.
The concept of moral hazard, where individuals take on more risk because they're insured, is a key contributor to adverse selection. As seen in the case of a 30-year-old driver with a clean record, who may be more likely to take on risks behind the wheel because they have insurance.
Insurance companies often respond to adverse selection by increasing premiums or denying coverage to high-risk individuals. For example, a study found that insurance companies raised premiums by 15% for drivers with a history of accidents.
The consequences of adverse selection can be severe, leading to a decrease in the overall quality of insurance policies.
Real-World Applications
Adverse selection insurance has real-world implications that affect us all. In the US, for example, the Affordable Care Act aimed to mitigate adverse selection by requiring individuals to purchase health insurance, regardless of their health status.
This approach has been successful in increasing the number of insured individuals. By 2016, the uninsured rate had dropped to 9.1%, a significant decrease from 16.3% in 2010.
Insurance companies often use risk classification to determine premiums. In the UK, for instance, smokers are typically charged higher premiums than non-smokers. This is because smokers are more likely to develop smoking-related illnesses.
As a result, smokers may be more likely to opt out of purchasing insurance, creating a pool of healthier, lower-risk individuals. This can lead to higher premiums for the remaining insured individuals.
In the case of the UK's National Health Service (NHS), the government has implemented measures to reduce adverse selection. One such measure is the requirement for individuals to pay a monthly premium for certain services, such as dental care.
Sources
- https://pmc.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/articles/PMC3248809/
- https://www.economicsonline.co.uk/definitions/adverse-selection-in-insurance.html/
- https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/adverseselection.asp
- https://www.britannica.com/money/adverse-selection
- https://lewisellis.com/specialties/health-care-reform-policy/moral-hazard-and-adverse-selection/
Featured Images: pexels.com