
Adverse selection is a real phenomenon that affects various aspects of our lives, including capital markets. It occurs when the least desirable or riskiest individuals or entities are more likely to participate in a market or activity.
In capital markets, adverse selection can lead to a decrease in the overall quality of the market. This can happen when investors with lower creditworthiness are more likely to take on debt, making it riskier for lenders.
Adverse selection is not limited to capital markets; it can also be observed in other areas such as insurance and labor markets. For instance, in the insurance industry, adverse selection can occur when individuals with higher health risks are more likely to purchase insurance, increasing the costs for other policyholders.
This can lead to a situation where only the riskiest individuals are left in the market, making it less attractive for others to participate.
What Is
Adverse selection is a scenario where either the buyer or the seller has information about an aspect of product quality that the other party does not have.
This can lead to people in high-risk lifestyles or those engaged in dangerous jobs signing up for insurance coverage as a way of protecting themselves from impending risk.
Insurance companies reduce their exposure to such high-risk claims by limiting coverage to such categories of people.
They can also raise the premium commensurately with the level of risk exposure as a way of compensating the company for the risk of covering high-risk policyholders.
Causes and Effects
Adverse selection occurs when one party in a transaction possesses more accurate information compared to the other party.
This information imbalance causes inefficiency in the price charged on specific goods or services, which can lead to losses for the party with less accurate information.
In the insurance sector, for example, a health insurance company may end up with a membership consisting mainly of people with health problems.
These individuals are more likely to think that the insurance is a great deal because they believe they'll spend more than the premium on healthcare bills.
Healthy individuals, on the other hand, may opt out of the insurance, thinking they won't need it.
This is because the party with more accurate information stands to gain more from the transaction, while the other party is at a disadvantage.
The health plan loses money because it's paying out more than it's taking in, which can lead to financial instability.
If the health insurance company doesn't do something to prevent this adverse selection, it will eventually lose so much money it won't be able to continue to pay claims.
Examples and Models
Adverse selection can be seen in the way people choose to purchase insurance policies. The diabetic person in Example 1 may conceal their health condition to get similar treatment as a healthy person.
In Example 2, adverse selection occurs when individuals with higher risk factors purchase insurance, knowing they are more likely to file claims. This can lead to a death spiral, where insurers raise premiums to cover increased claims, causing more individuals to opt out of the plan.
A health insurance company may sell a plan for $500 per month, but a 64-year-old person with diabetes and heart disease may see this as a great deal, while a healthy 20-year-old man may not. This is an example of adverse selection, where the plan's membership consists mainly of people with health problems.
Capital Markets
Capital markets can be a breeding ground for adverse selection, where companies that are struggling to find funding are more likely to offer securities at a lower price. This can lead to a situation where outside investors are left with less desirable offerings.
Adverse selection costs are lower for debt offerings, which act as a signal to outside investors that the firm's management believes the current stock price is undervalued. This is because debt offerings don't reveal as much information about the company's internal value as equity offerings do.
In fact, debt should be cheaper than equity as a source of external capital, forming a "pecking order". This is because debt offerings don't come with the same level of risk as equity offerings, which can be prone to adverse selection.
The presence of adverse selection in capital markets results in excessive private investment, where projects that wouldn't normally receive funding due to having a lower expected return than the opportunity cost of capital, receive funding anyway due to information asymmetry in the market.
Here's a breakdown of the types of securities that are more prone to adverse selection:
- Equity offerings
- High-growth company equity offerings
These types of securities are more likely to be affected by adverse selection because they reveal more information about the company's internal value, making it easier for outside investors to make informed decisions.
Mortgage Market
The mortgage market is a prime example of how adverse selection can affect a market. Adverse selection with asymmetric information in the mortgage market can lead to a lower price margin on loans and portfolios in the market.
In the case of commercial mortgages, unequal information on the secondary market loans can reinforce the conduit on lenders about the mortgage quality and information. This can effectively consider the effect of adverse selection, leading to a lower price margin on loans and portfolios in the market.
To mitigate the effects of adverse selection, banks have moved towards building stronger relationships with their customers. This helps in further understanding some of the hidden information the consumers have when they are borrowing from banks.
Banks can also adjust interest rates to help alleviate some of the unknown risks involved. They have implemented heavier screening on loan applicants so that they are receiving the full picture when they lend their money to borrowers.
Here are some key factors that contribute to adverse selection in the mortgage market:
- Asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers
- Unequal information on secondary market loans
- Lower price margin on loans and portfolios
- Heavier screening on loan applicants
- Adjusting interest rates to mitigate unknown risks
By understanding these factors, lenders can take steps to mitigate the effects of adverse selection and create a more efficient mortgage market.
A Model of Hidden Attributes
Adverse selection occurs when one party in a transaction possesses more accurate information compared to the other party. This information imbalance causes inefficiency in the price charged on specific goods or services.
In the insurance sector, a 64-year-old person with diabetes and heart disease is likely to purchase a health insurance plan because they think it's a good deal, despite the fact that the plan will likely pay out more in claims than it takes in premiums.

The presence of adverse selection in capital markets results in excessive private investment, as projects that would not have received investments due to having a lower expected return than the opportunity cost of capital, receive funding as a result of information asymmetry in the market.
Banks have implemented various safeguards to limit the effects of adverse selection on their business, including building stronger relationships with customers, adjusting interest rates, and implementing heavier screening on loan applicants.
A manufacturer may be more accurate than a supplier in predicting demand for their products, creating an information asymmetry that can lead to adverse selection.
In the case of life insurance, a diabetic person may conceal their health condition to get similar treatment as a healthy person, leading to adverse selection.
Adverse selection models can be categorized into models with private values and models with interdependent or common values. In models with private values, the agent's type has a direct influence on his own preferences.
A table summarizing the key differences between adverse selection and moral hazard models is below:
Solutions and Mitigation
To mitigate adverse selection, insurance companies can group high-risk individuals and charge them higher premiums based on factors such as age, health condition, weight, medical history, hobbies, lifestyle risk, driving record, and occupation.
Insurance companies can also reduce adverse selection by encouraging transparency between both sides of the market, which helps eliminate asymmetric information.
Insurance companies can charge different premium rates to clients depending on various factors, including age, health condition, and lifestyle risk, which can impact a person's health and life expectancy.
Here are some examples of insurance types that are commonly affected by adverse selection:
Contract Theory
Contract theory is a complex field that helps us understand how contracts are formed and negotiated. In modern contract theory, "adverse selection" is a key concept that characterizes principal-agent models where an agent has private information before a contract is written.
Adverse selection models can be categorized into models with private values and models with interdependent or common values. The former occurs when the agent's type has a direct influence on his own preferences, while the latter occurs when the agent's type has a direct influence on the principal's preferences.
Roger Myerson and Eric Maskin have made seminal contributions to private value models, while George Akerlof first studied interdependent or common value models. This distinction is crucial in understanding how contracts are formed and negotiated.
In adverse selection models, the agent's private information is often assumed to be "soft" and cannot be certified. However, there are also models with "hard" information, where the agent may have evidence to prove that claims he makes about his type are true.
Adverse selection models can be further categorized into models with one-sided private information and two-sided private information. The most prominent result in the latter case is the Myerson-Satterthwaite theorem, which has been influential in contract theory.
Warranties
Warranties can be a powerful tool for conveying information about a product's quality to potential buyers.
Offering a warranty for a product indirectly communicates private information about the product to the buyer.
In the used car market, warranties are often used to demonstrate the seller's confidence in the product's quality.
A warranty can act as a guarantee on the product, providing peace of mind for the buyer.
Buyers may also purchase additional warranties in the form of insurance from third-party companies.
Solution

Insurance companies can avoid adverse selection by grouping high-risk individuals and charging them higher premiums based on factors like age, health condition, weight, medical history, and occupation.
One way to determine the premium is to consider the person's lifestyle risk, such as obesity, smoking, and diabetes, which can impact their health and life expectancy.
Insurance companies can also charge different premium rates to clients depending on their driving record and hobbies.
To reduce adverse selection, it's essential to eliminate asymmetric information by encouraging transparency between buyers and sellers in the market.
The key to reducing adverse selection is to encourage transparency, which can be achieved by making information about the product or service easily available to both sides of the market.
By doing so, buyers and sellers can make informed decisions, and market efficiencies can be improved.
The Affordable Care Act (ACA) required all legal residents of the U.S. to have health insurance or pay a tax penalty from 2014 to 2018.

This requirement encouraged younger, healthier people to enroll in a health plan, which helped to prevent adverse selection.
However, the penalty was eliminated after 2018, which led to an increase in individual market premiums due to adverse selection.
The Congressional Budget Office estimated that the elimination of the penalty would result in individual market premiums that are 10% higher each year.
States like Massachusetts, New Jersey, Rhode Island, and California have acted on their own to require residents to maintain health coverage or pay a penalty on their state tax returns.
These states have taken steps to prevent adverse selection in their insurance markets, similar to the federal government's individual mandate under the ACA.
Here are some types of insurance that can help mitigate adverse selection:
- Health insurance
- Life insurance
- Business insurance
- Residential insurance
- Transport/Communication insurance
- Other types of insurance
Insurance
Adverse selection in insurance is a real concern, and it's not just limited to the health insurance industry. In fact, the concept of adverse selection was first used to describe the likelihood that people who elect to purchase insurance policies will file claims that exceed the total dollar value of the premiums they pay.
Insurance companies use risk factors to set premiums, but individuals who know they have higher risk factors may opt out of the plan if premiums are too high. This can create a "death spiral" where only high-risk individuals remain in the plan, increasing the likelihood of claims and further driving up premiums.
The Affordable Care Act (ACA) limited insurers' ability to prevent adverse selection by prohibiting them from refusing to sell health insurance to people with pre-existing conditions. This means that insurers can't use medical underwriting to determine who's a good risk and who's not.
The ACA also requires insurers to charge the same premium to people with pre-existing conditions as they do to healthy people. This can be a challenge for insurers, as they may end up paying out more in claims than they collect in premiums.
To mitigate the effects of adverse selection, the ACA introduced a risk adjustment program. This program requires insurers to pay into a pool if their plans attract healthier enrollees, and it provides a payout to insurers if their plans attract sicker enrollees.
Here's a breakdown of the ACA's risk adjustment program:
Note that this is just a simplified example, and actual risk adjustment payments can be much more complex.
The ACA's risk adjustment program is designed to encourage insurers to offer plans that appeal to people with high-cost medical conditions, rather than trying to avoid them. This helps to reduce the impact of adverse selection and ensure that everyone has access to affordable health insurance.
Frequently Asked Questions
What is adverse selection vs moral hazard?
Adverse selection and moral hazard are two types of market failures that occur when individuals make decisions based on incomplete or biased information, leading to undesirable outcomes. Adverse selection happens when one party acts on bad info, while moral hazard occurs when someone takes more risks knowing others will cover the costs
Sources
- https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Adverse_selection
- https://www.core-econ.org/the-economy/microeconomics/10-market-successes-failures-10-hidden-attributes.html
- https://www.britannica.com/money/adverse-selection
- https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/wealth-management/adverse-selection/
- https://www.verywellhealth.com/adverse-selection-what-it-is-how-health-plans-avoid-it-1738416
Featured Images: pexels.com