Risk Aversion Psychology in Everyday Life

Author

Reads 1.1K

A Man Placing Bets on the Roulette Table
Credit: pexels.com, A Man Placing Bets on the Roulette Table

Risk aversion psychology plays a significant role in our daily lives, influencing our decisions and behaviors in subtle yet profound ways. We tend to avoid risks that could lead to financial losses or physical harm, as seen in the example of the 50/30/20 rule, where people allocate a significant portion of their income towards necessities to minimize financial risk.

Our brains are wired to respond to potential threats, making us more cautious in situations where we perceive uncertainty. This is evident in the concept of loss aversion, where the pain of losing something is greater than the pleasure of gaining something of equal value.

In everyday life, risk aversion psychology can manifest in various ways, such as in our reluctance to try new foods or take on new challenges. This can be attributed to the fear of failure or the unknown, which can be overwhelming and uncomfortable.

Theories and Concepts

Risk aversion theories often depict each option as a gamble with various outcomes and probabilities. Theories like Expected Utility Theory (EUT) and Prospect Theory (PT) are widely accepted, but they arrive at risk aversion indirectly.

These theories use a value function to index the attractiveness of outcomes, a weighting function to quantify the impact of probabilities, and combine them to establish a utility for each course of action. This last step, combining value and weight, remains sub-optimal in EUT and PT.

Psychological Factors

Credit: youtube.com, Risk aversion and risk seeking - Leader decisions from psychological perspectives

Our emotions play a significant role in how we perceive risk and make decisions. People base their judgments of an activity or technology not only on what they think about it but also on how they feel about it.

Research has shown that the strength of positive or negative affect associated with an activity is linked to the inverse relation between perceived risk and perceived benefit. If your feelings toward an activity are favorable, you're more likely to judge the risks as low and the benefits as high.

Emotions can either benefit or hinder the attainment of maximized utility, making decision making and emotion intertwined. Your current emotional state, past emotional state, and future emotional state all influence decision making.

Here are the three different emotional states that influence decision making:

  • Your current emotional state (i.e. how do you feel while you are making a decision?)
  • Your past emotional state (i.e. how did you feel anticipating your decision?)
  • Your future emotional state (i.e. how will your decision affect how you feel in the future; what effect will the decision have on your emotional well-being?)

Affective Psychology

Affective psychology is a fascinating field that explores the role of emotions in decision-making. Emotions can significantly influence how we perceive risks and benefits, leading to judgments that may not be entirely rational. For instance, a study by Alhakami and Slovic (1994) found that people tend to judge activities with favorable emotions as having low risks and high benefits.

For your interest: Benefits of Risk Taking

Credit: youtube.com, Emotion, Stress, and Health: Crash Course Psychology #26

Our emotional state can either benefit or hinder our goal attainment. Decision making and emotion are intertwined, making it challenging to separate them. Emotions can either motivate us to take action or hold us back.

There are three key emotional states that influence decision making: our current emotional state, our past emotional state, and our future emotional state. Our current emotional state can impact our decision-making process, while our past emotional state can influence our expectations and attitudes towards a particular decision. On the other hand, our future emotional state can affect how we feel about the consequences of our decisions.

Interestingly, research has shown that people tend to be loss averse, meaning they fear losses more than they value gains. However, not everyone displays the same level of loss aversion, and certain groups, such as economists and professional traders, tend to exhibit lower levels of loss aversion on average.

Here's a breakdown of the three emotional states that influence decision making:

Understanding these emotional states can help us make more informed decisions and avoid pitfalls that may lead to regret. By acknowledging the role of emotions in decision-making, we can take steps to manage our emotions and make choices that align with our goals and values.

Children

Credit: youtube.com, Ripple Effect: Parental Mental Illness and Children's Risk Factors

Children need to have a certain amount of risk taking in their lives so they can learn to solve problems for themselves.

Many playgrounds have been fitted with impact-absorbing matting surfaces, but these are only designed to save children from death in the case of direct falls on their heads.

This type of risk-averse planning can prevent children from benefiting from activities they would otherwise have had, such as building a playground closer to their home, which could reduce the risk of a road traffic accident on the way to it.

Children who are only ever kept in very safe places are not the ones who are able to solve problems for themselves.

In the Brain

The brain plays a crucial role in risk aversion psychology.

The right inferior frontal gyrus is a specific brain area that has been linked to risk aversion.

Research by Christopoulos et al. in 2009 found that the activity of this area correlates with risk aversion, with risk averse participants having higher responses to safer options.

Credit: youtube.com, Risk Aversion - Your Mental Health Minute

This suggests that the brain's activity can influence our risk-taking behavior.

Neuromodulation of the right inferior frontal gyrus has also been shown to affect risk aversion, with increased activity leading to more cautious choices and decreased activity leading to riskier decisions.

The brain's ability to modulate risk aversion highlights the complex interplay between emotions, cognition, and decision-making.

Behavioral Biases

Prospect theory shows that we tend to place a larger value on a loss than on a gain of the same amount. This is known as loss aversion, a fundamental bias that affects our decision-making.

Loss aversion is a complex behavioral bias that causes us to be risk-averse over gains and risk-seeking over losses. It's centered around a set reference point or status quo, which can be subjective and vary from person to person or scenario to scenario.

In a high-stakes context, professional golfers' performance on the PGA TOUR was analyzed, and it was found that golfers play better when attempting to avoid dropping a shot than when trying to gain one. This loss-aversion equates to $1.2 million in tournament winnings per year.

Credit: youtube.com, Prospect Theory (explained in a minute) - Behavioural Finance

The disposition effect is another manifestation of loss aversion in our investing decisions. We tend to hold onto shares that have made a loss, but sell shares that have made a profit.

Here are some key characteristics of the disposition effect:

  • Continuing to hold onto shares that have made a loss
  • Selling shares that have made a profit
  • Risk-averse with gains, risk-seeking with losses
  • Regret avoidance is also at play

This behavior is not rational, as John Maynard Keynes famously said: "It's hard to see how any rational man can ever invest."

Investment and Decision Making

Risk aversion plays a crucial role in investment decisions, as individuals tend to prefer sure outcomes over uncertain ones.

According to the von Neumann-Morgenstern utility theorem, individuals seek to maximize their expected utility rather than the expected monetary value of assets.

This means that a risk-averse individual may prefer to keep their savings rather than gamble it all to potentially increase their wealth.

In modern portfolio theory, risk aversion is measured as the additional expected reward an investor requires to accept additional risk.

A risk-averse investor will invest in multiple uncertain assets only when the predicted return on a portfolio that is uncertain is greater than the predicted return on one that is not uncertain.

A different take: Risk Return Tradeoff

Credit: youtube.com, Risk aversion and risk seeking - Leader decisions from psychological perspectives (Updated 2022)

The risk-return spectrum is relevant here, as it results largely from this type of risk aversion.

Risk is measured as the standard deviation of the return on investment, i.e. the square root of its variance.

To overcome cognitive biases and make rational investment decisions, it's essential to understand behavioral finance and loss psychology.

Losses can have a value if you learn from them and look at things dispassionately and strategically.

To break free from their fear of financial losses, successful investors incorporate "loss psychology" into their investment strategies and use coping strategies.

Here are some key differences in risk aversion between individuals with different levels of wealth:

Understanding and Managing Risk Aversion

Loss aversion is a powerful force that affects our decision-making. We tend to fear losses more than we value gains.

Prospective losses bother individuals much more than prospective gains, which is why we often make choices based on the subjective version of a situation rather than the objective reality.

Credit: youtube.com, Utility and Risk Preferences Part 1 - Utility Function

Understanding this can help you make better financial decisions. A good example of a product designed to take advantage of loss aversion is insurance policies, which highlight the potential loss to create an anchor pushing us to choose the option that avoids such losses.

Highlighting the potential loss can also be a effective way to convince someone of something. For instance, instead of telling someone that quitting drinking will lead to better job opportunities, you can tell them that it will help them avoid losing their spouse and children.

How to Manage

We tend to fear losses more than we value gains. This is what sets loss aversion apart from risk aversion.

Prospective losses can be much more bothersome than prospective gains.

To make informed decisions, it's essential to distinguish between price and value.

Insurance policies are designed to take advantage of our loss aversion by highlighting potential losses.

Focusing on how something can help you avoid disadvantages can be a more effective approach than highlighting its advantages.

For instance, you could tell someone that quitting drinking might help them avoid losing their spouse and children, rather than telling them they could get a better job and earn more money.

Understanding

Credit: youtube.com, 'Understanding and Managing Risk Culture Dr Simon Ashby

Loss aversion is a powerful force that can significantly impact our investment decisions. Humans are wired for loss aversion, one of many cognitive biases identified by behavioral economists.

Losses lead to more extreme emotional responses than gains, causing investors to behave irrationally and make poor decisions. This can result in holding onto losing investments long after they should have been sold.

The pain of losing is psychologically about twice as powerful as the joy we experience when winning, making it even more challenging to make rational decisions. This is known as the disposition effect.

Loss aversion can lead to negativity bias, causing investors to put more weight on bad news than on good news. This can cause them to miss out on bull markets and panic when markets sell-off.

Check this out: Santa Claus Rally News

Social and Cultural Aspects

Government agencies like the Health and Safety Executive are fundamentally risk-averse in their mandate, often demanding that risks be minimized, even if it means losing the utility of the activity.

Credit: youtube.com, risk aversion and applications

This approach can lead to a focus on minimizing risk without considering the opportunity cost of not taking the risky action. The cost of not taking the action can be significant.

In fact, Cambridge University recognized the importance of public understanding of risk in 2007, initiating the Winton Professorship of the Public Understanding of Risk, which focuses on outreach rather than traditional academic research.

Societal Applications

In the real world, many government agencies, like the Health and Safety Executive, are fundamentally risk-averse in their mandate, often demanding that risks be minimized, even at the cost of losing the utility of the activity.

This approach can misrepresent society's goals, as it focuses on minimizing risk without considering the opportunity cost of not taking the risky action.

The public understanding of risk plays a significant role in shaping political decisions, which is why Cambridge University initiated the Winton Professorship of the Public Understanding of Risk in 2007.

Credit: youtube.com, The Secret Life of Social Norms | Michele Gelfand, PhD | TEDxPaloAltoSalon

People often show direct risk aversion by valuing a risky prospect below the value of its worst possible outcome, as seen in the popularity of insurance policies with low deductibles.

Reducing a risk by half may not be worth half the premium, which is why people often find probabilistic insurance unattractive.

This aversion to probabilistic insurance undermines the classical explanation of insurance in terms of a concave utility function, as it suggests that people prefer complete elimination of risk over reduction of risk.

Insurance policies can be framed in different ways, with some being more attractive than others, such as framing a policy that covers fire but not flood as full protection against a specific risk rather than a reduction in overall probability of property loss.

Research has shown that people undervalue a reduction in the probability of a hazard in comparison to the complete elimination of that hazard, which is why insurance should appear more attractive when framed as the elimination of risk.

Impression Management

Credit: youtube.com, Impression management | Individuals and Society | MCAT | Khan Academy

Impression management is a clever tactic used to manipulate people's perceptions. It's a field of study that helps companies make their earnings announcements and annual reports more palatable.

Companies use impression management to overwhelm you with information you don't need to understand, making it hard to grasp the not-so-good news. This is a common practice.

Using symbols instead of words can draw your attention to important information, making it harder to ignore. It's like when you see a big red flag waving, you can't help but notice.

Prospect theory tells us that people tend to feel the pain of a loss more than the pleasure of a gain. This means that companies can use this to their advantage by drip-feeding good news throughout a report, making you almost forget the bad news earlier on.

Dividing bonuses into smaller mini-bonuses throughout the year can maximize the utility received by employees, according to prospect theory. It's like getting a series of small treats instead of one big one.

Broaden your view: Risk Appetite News

Limitations of Expected Utility

Credit: youtube.com, Expected Utility (1): Risk Aversion, Risk Loving, and Risk Neutral

Expected utility theory's approach to risk aversion has some major limitations. One of them is that it can lead to implausible conclusions, such as a risk-averse individual turning down 50-50 bets of losing $1,000 or gaining any sum of money.

Matthew Rabin criticized this implication of expected utility theory, pointing out that it's unrealistic for people to exhibit extreme forms of risk aversion in large-stakes decisions if they're risk-averse for small gambles.

Prospect theory and cumulative prospect theory offer an alternative approach, considering outcomes relative to a reference point rather than just the final wealth. This makes more sense, as people's preferences often depend on their current situation.

The reflection effect is another limitation of expected utility theory. It shows that people tend to avoid risk when the gamble is between gains, but seek risks when the gamble is between losses. For example, most people prefer a certain gain of $3,000 to an 80% chance of a gain of $4,000, but prefer an 80% chance of a loss of $4,000 to a certain loss of $3,000.

The reflection effect is inconsistent with the expected utility hypothesis, and it's assumed that the psychological principle behind this behavior is the overweighting of certainty.

Helen Stokes

Assigning Editor

Helen Stokes is a seasoned Assigning Editor with a passion for storytelling and a keen eye for detail. With a background in journalism, she has honed her skills in researching and assigning articles on a wide range of topics. Her expertise lies in the realm of numismatics, with a particular focus on commemorative coins and Canadian currency.

Love What You Read? Stay Updated!

Join our community for insights, tips, and more.